Showing posts with label iPad. Show all posts
Showing posts with label iPad. Show all posts

Sunday, April 22, 2012

Government Woefully Unprepared for Market Innovation, Part 7491

I've discussed "3D printing" before, but a new must-read article from The Economist explains just how the new technology is causing a "Third Industrial Revolution."  The whole article is worth reading, but I was particularly struck by this discussion of the revolutionary technology's immense impact on national policy:
Consumers will have little difficulty adapting to the new age of better products, swiftly delivered. Governments, however, may find it harder. Their instinct is to protect industries and companies that already exist, not the upstarts that would destroy them. They shower old factories with subsidies and bully bosses who want to move production abroad. They spend billions backing the new technologies which they, in their wisdom, think will prevail. And they cling to a romantic belief that manufacturing is superior to services, let alone finance.

None of this makes sense. The lines between manufacturing and services are blurring. Rolls-Royce no longer sells jet engines; it sells the hours that each engine is actually thrusting an aeroplane through the sky. Governments have always been lousy at picking winners, and they are likely to become more so, as legions of entrepreneurs and tinkerers swap designs online, turn them into products at home and market them globally from a garage. As the revolution rages, governments should stick to the basics: better schools for a skilled workforce, clear rules and a level playing field for enterprises of all kinds. Leave the rest to the revolutionaries.
This all should scare the bejeebus out of those of us who advocate national trade and economic policies which reflect modern realities of today's markets.  Why?  Because our policymakers still haven't accepted obvious market phenomena that have been around for a decade or more, and thus develop and advocate archaic policies that actually serve to hurt domestic industries, workers and the economy more broadly.  For example, almost all US politicians - in both major parties - still kvetch about the US-China trade balance, even though study after study has demonstrated just how pointless that statistic has become in this era of global supply chains.  The latest example of that fact comes from this great new graphic (h/t ToGetRichIsGlorious) which shows the cost and profit breakdown of the iPad in 2010:


As you can see, of the of the $499 retail price, Apple (30.1%) and other US companies (2.4%) get 32.5 percent of the profits, while China gets only a tiny fraction of that (1.6%).  Yet 100% of the iPad's US customs value adds to the US-China trade deficit.  So why on earth do our politicians act like this bilateral deficit - or any bilateral trade deficit for that matter - should form the basis for US-China trade policy?  It's simply mind-boggling.

Another common example of the gaping market-politics disconnect that I've frequently lamented - and one hinted by the story above - is our politicians' continued fetishization of manufacturing (and manufacturing employment).  It warms my heart that a few politicians appear to be getting the message about services, as this recent and (mostly) refreshing op-ed from US Trade Representative Ron Kirk demonstrates:
The United States today is a services trading powerhouse, and it's vital that we build on our already robust services surplus with dynamic new opportunities...

Next month, the U.S. will host the 12th round of negotiations in the Trans-Pacific Partnership. Those critical talks will follow closely on the heels of a number of key engagements with America's global trading partners, including last week's Summit of the Americas, this week's meetings of the G-20 trade ministers, and May's Strategic and Economic Dialogue with China. In June, the trade ministers of the Asia-Pacific Economic Cooperation forum (APEC) will meet in Russia.

In all of these fora, the U.S. will be seeking new avenues for American businesses to sell more of their products around the world, and to hire more workers in the services sector, which already accounts for four out of five American jobs.

The U.S. is the largest services trading country in the world, with $1 trillion in two-way trade in 2011 and a services trade surplus last year of $179 billion (up 23% from 2010). In what economist Bradford Jensen defines as the fastest-growing services sectors, Bureau of Economic Analysis data show that the U.S. in 2010 had a trade surplus of $57 billion with the Asia-Pacific region, of $44 billion with the European Union, of $35 billion with the countries covered by the North American Free Trade Agreement (Canada and Mexico), and of $25 billion with the rest of Latin America....
If some of those data sound familiar, they should - they mirror several of the points that I made in December about America's globally-dominant services sector (and politicians' ignorance thereof).  The aforementioned op-ed goes on to explain some of the (mostly good) things that USTR is doing to further expand US service suppliers' access to foreign markets, but unfortunately, Kirk's boss doesn't seem to share the love for the US service sector.  Instead, most of President Obama's tax and trade policies are geared toward boosting the US manufacturing sector (at the services sector's expense, naturally) - a troubling disconnect that I've noted repeatedly.  So while USTR Kirk's services affinity is certainly a welcome development, it's a bit less exciting when one considers the archaic and misguided policies pushed by the rest of his colleagues in the Obama administration.

And this gets me back to 3D printing and the "Third Industrial Revolution."  If our very "modern" and "progressive" government (and other governments like it) still refuses to recognize and adapt to simple and obvious market developments that have been going on for decades now, what hope does it have in recognizing and adapting to the more complicated and revolutionary things that are happening right now?

If the trade-related examples above are any indication, the answer to that question is as depressing as it is obvious.  That answer also should inform our faith in government policy accepting and adapting to other critical market phenomena too.  Maybe, just maybe, highly complex things like industrial policy or nationalized healthcare aren't very good ideas after all, huh?

Crazy thought, I know.

Monday, May 9, 2011

Monday Quick Hits

It's been a while since I last cleared the decks, so these headlines will go back a couple weeks:

That should keep y'all busy for a while. 

Saturday, February 20, 2010

UK to US: Your Mercantilist Trade Policy Is Bollocks

I stumbled across a recent blog entry by British Trade Policy Adviser Patrick Thomas that lauds recent US efforts to expand trade but, in typical British fashion, politely explains why the UK's new trade policies are far better (emphasis mine, silly UK spelling his):
[I]t is encouraging that here in Washington, policymakers are talking seriously about engaging with the world through trade. After a year in which trade policy did not feature prominently, President Obama used his State of the Union Address to announce an ambitious plan to double US exports in five years. His Commerce Secretary, Gary Locke, claims that the plan would also support two million jobs in the United States.

Expanding trade is a way to boost economic growth and create jobs, and one that I recommended in my last blog. And in fact, the UK has a comprehensive strategy called 'New Industries, New Jobs', which sees an important role for exports as a driver of growth. What's interesting about the strategy is that it emphasises that exports are only one piece of the puzzle. It recognises that the UK cannot efficiently produce everything by itself. What's key is preparing workers for the high-paying jobs in the industries of tomorrow. To pursue this agenda, it is necessary to recognise that both inward and outward trade flows figure in greater prosperity.

Indeed, modern trade theory tells us that imports are just as important as exports...

The UK has long embraced open trade as a policy, which has played a key role in making Britain a wealthier, more dynamic and more diverse society. So let's promote exports, but let's not forget the benefits of imports as well....
The loud *thud* sound you hear is me falling our of my chair.  Thomas even cited the iPod as an example of how nations benefit from, and thus should embrace, specialization and modern global supply chains.  Good for him.  And great for the UK for adopting a commonsense, 21st century trade policy and (again, politely) calling attention to the asininity of American mercantilism.

If only the White House were listening.

Wednesday, January 27, 2010

Explaining the iPad's "Stunning" Price

After months of intense nerd-blog speculation, Apple's Steve Jobs today unveiled his company's latest gadget, the iPad:
Steve Jobs took the stage Wednesday to sell the world on one of his biggest gambles since returning to Apple Inc. nearly 15 years ago: a multimedia tablet-style computer called the iPad.

The 9.7-inch touch-screen iPad, which will let users play games, check email, and read books, presents a major challenge to the media, publishing and wireless industries. For Mr. Jobs, it is an attempt to convince consumers they need yet another gadget—one between their mobile phones and laptop computers.
The iPad is basically an iPhone with a bigger, badder HD screen and e-reader capability, but other than its (admittedly high) "cool factor," the gadget wasn't received as that revolutionary.

Well, that's until Jobs unveiled the ridiculously low price:
Yes, Apple's iPad is revolutionary–but mainly because it's cheap.

By offering the tablet computer for as low as $499, Apple has found a way to meet demand for low-priced laptops without a radical price cut on its Mac line. Yet its cheaper computer not only has all the utilitarian functions of a laptop, such as word processing and email, but enhanced entertainment capabilities as well. And it can run iPhone mobile applications.
The highest priced iPad will be only about $800, and that's pretty amazing.  How amazing, you ask?  Well, according to one tech investment website, the iPad's price announcement caused Apple's stock to stage a serious midday turnaround:
Strangely, during the course of the much-anticipated event, Apple’s stock went down, as observed by many. And then, Apple finally got around to talking about pricing.

Chief executive Steve Jobs took the stage, and wowed the crowd (and the world) by saying that the starting price for the iPad was a stunning $499.

Guess what happened next?

At the time of this writing, the stock spiked +3.61.

We wouldn’t be surprised to see it hit an all-time high today.
Jobs' price announcement happened around 2:20p EST, and look what happened immediately after that:



Pretty cool, huh?  Now, how do you think that Apple got the iPad's base price to be about half of its cheapest Mac laptop?  Well, assuming the iPad's anything like its little cousin the iPod, the answer is simple: free trade.  As Dan Ikenson and I discussed in our 2009 study (PDF):
A 2007 study published by the University of California–Irvine sought to determine “who captures value in a global innovation system” by disaggregating the components contained in an Apple iPod and determining the companies and countries involved in manufacturing a unit in China. The authors found that the components were produced in the United States, Japan, Singapore, Taiwan, Korea, and China by companies headquartered in the United States, Japan, Taiwan, and Korea. The total cost of producing the iPod (components plus labor) was estimated to be about $144. Most of the profits on the constituent components accrue to Japanese companies, who produce the most important and most expensive parts. Two U.S. and some other foreign components’ producers all capture small shares of the value. But the lion’s share of value accrues to Apple since iPods retail for $299 and the cost of production is $144 (at the time this article was written)....

Without access to assembly operations in lower-cost countries, the mass production and proliferation of iPods and similar devices likely would not have been possible. Instead of $299, iPods would cost perhaps $500 or more if they had to be produced entirely in the United States. At that price point, it is unlikely that sales of iPods would ever have been as successful as they have been, and the need for all of those American jobs in engineering, logistics, transportation, advertising, web design, and retailing might never have materialized.
(This awesome video by ReasonTV makes a similar - yet bikini-clad - argument.)

Now, a full "teardown" of the iPad isn't available yet (of course) and won't be for a while, but based on the limited information that I could find, it appears that Apple's iPad emerged from much the same global sourcing and development strategy as the ubiquitous iPod.  Taiwanese manufacturers produced the iPad's batteries, display panels and other guts (note: not a technical term).  A US semiconductor design firm, PA Semi (purchased by Apple in 2008) designed the iPad's revolutionary A4 processor, and had it manufactured (or "fabbed," as the techies say) in either Korea or Texas (nobody's quite sure of that yet).  Korean manufacturers are also rumored to have produced a few other component parts, and all of them were assembled in China.

So again we see the same Apple recipe: (i) research, development, design, marketing and some manufacturing in the United States; (ii) component production in Taiwan and other foreign countries; (iii) and final assembly in China.

The result?  A hyper-competitively priced product that's destined to excite consumers and further enrich Apple, its American employees, and, as today's stock boost makes quite clear, its many happy shareholders.